Thank you, Mr. Chair.
I'm sorry, I was travelling a bit and didn't have time to finish my text in time, but I will get it to the committee in both languages in the next few days. I'll try to hit a few of the high points.
I have reviewed what's been happening before you over the last few weeks, and it seems to me that the principal reasons why a more competitive agricultural sector in Canada is being inhibited are: a lack of free and open markets internationally; the pervasive and extensive use of subsidies by primarily the United States and the EU, but also other countries; excessive interference in the market due to sanitary and phytosanitary concerns that are not based in science; the disparity in size and market power between farmers and ranchers and their suppliers and customers; and frustration with the apparently contradictory goals of competition policy in Canada.
I was quite interested to review your hearings with the Competition Bureau, and a number of the members seemed to experience frustration. I would attribute that to the dual goals of Canadian competition policy, on the one hand to ensure that there's competitiveness in our marketplaces and on the other hand to not apply the rules so tightly that the large players in a rather small market are not prevented from competing internationally with much bigger players.
My normal focus is trade negotiations and trade policy, and international competition is the essential focus of trade policy. If we're not competitive, we won't be able to take advantage of the access we negotiate internationally, so competition is extremely important. But when it comes to competition issues, the farmer is really the ham in the sandwich. It's a function of size. There are tools to deal with abuse of marketing power, but these seem to run head-on into the dual responsibility of the competition law administrators.
With very few exceptions, farmers are dealing with oligopolies, in terms of their suppliers, and oligopsonies, in terms of their customers. The disadvantages of dealing with these customers can be reduced by joint selling activities, such as those that exist in supply-managed sectors and where there are government-mandated marketing boards.
As for suppliers, it's more difficult to cope with that because rationalization within North America in particular has led to consolidation, which has reduced competition and goes right across the board. For many farmers this lack of competition on both ends reduces their gross margins and incomes.
In the brief introductory period I have available to me, I want to touch a little on what's happening in our international competitive markets. There are still very heavy subsidies to the grains and oilseeds sectors in the United States and Europe. These subsidies promote the competitiveness of the livestock, poultry, and dairy industries in those countries.
On recent developments, the USDA was appropriated $28 billion in a stimulus package for U.S. farmers. Almost $20 billion of that is to increase the monthly amount of nutrition assistance, and that's about 40% of their normal budget.
There is money for other factors. The Farm Bill has expanded its scope. It's still very generous and it still deals with the basic root problems we have in competing in the grains and oilseeds sector and through the chain.
Just this morning the European Union decided--they've been looking at it for a while, so it's not an overnight decision--that direct payments, their so-called decoupled payments that aren't decoupled, will be much less relevant in the common agricultural policy beyond 2013.
I think I sent members of the committee a copy of the release this morning, but you may not have it yet.
This is very intriguing because the Europeans have nearly 30 countries and 30 agriculture ministers, all with different views, and Commissioner Fischer Boel with a view of her own, which is probably very appropriate. On the one hand, you have the Nordic countries like Sweden that would rather spend less and aren't terribly concerned about agriculture. On the other hand, you have the more southern countries.
The general view is that it is difficult to wean people off direct payments. One of the bigger problems appears to be that a number of the member states consider that in fact to be the modulation, as they call it—they have wonderful words, and that is where we get modalities, that is where we get modulation—of direct payment support into regional development support, from pillar one to pillar two, which has already gone too far.
They are not keen on more modulation. They are not keen on sharing for regional development. There are imbalances that have been pointed out by the new member states, in which the amount of direct aid per hectare, for example, in Greece is 20 times what it is in Latvia. So they are looking for a more uniform system within the EU.
What we can be sure of from what is said in that release is that the support to agriculture in the European Union is going to continue to be very generous.
Some of you may recall that when I appeared here a few years ago to talk to you about EU agricultural support, I characterized their single farm payment system as one that paid them support based on what they got in 2000 to 2002 and let them top up from the market. That works when the market is up, but when the market is down, as it is now, it creates problems.
That is why we've had Denmark trying to reinstitute its export restitutions on swine. The same thing has happened in France. In fact, there have been more general discussions on that issue within the European Union.
There have been problems with dairy throughout the European Union, and those problems, as they are with hogs, are related to significant oversupply and very low prices. The export restitutions on dairy have been reintroduced in the European Union, which has caused the United States to reintroduce the dairy export incentives program.
Mr. Chairman, we are in a race for the bottom, except Canada is not in the race. We don't have the money. We have never really dealt with export subsidies in that way, and we do have serious problems.
Other issues I'd be happy to touch on during the questions and answers relate to regulation and some of the deficiencies we see with the Food Inspection Agency. In my view, the Food Inspection Agency does a very good job of inspecting food in Canada, but it just doesn't have the staff or the funding to get involved in having other markets approved for us. And that is a serious matter. It takes far too long to negotiate these veterinary agreements. That could be addressed by funding.
Why do young farmers want to go into farming with all the uncertainties they face? The presentation the Canadian Pork Council made to you last week I believe touched on a lot of the problems that have affected the pork producers.
Pork producers and cattlemen deal with cyclical movements in the marketplace all the time. In some years there is too much and in other years there's not enough. The herd is either rebuilding or it's being culled. Those things they can deal with, but they really haven't been able to deal with the high grain prices, which were driven by U.S. energy policy. They haven't been able to cope with the dollar going up so rapidly. They haven't been able to cope with the country of origin labelling regulations and a number of others.
Why are young farmers going to go into farming unless they can really see something at the end of the road? I don't think we have the proper risk management policies to deal with that.
I was interested in Mr. Meredith's discussion with you and his staff on Bill C-29. It was all very interesting, but why are we putting people further into debt? That's not what's happening in other countries. There are grants in France for young farmers and other people.
I'll be happy to deal with this in more detail, Mr. Chairman. I think my ten minutes are up.