Thank you very much, and thank you for the invitation to speak to the committee.
I'm pleased that the committee has a really broad mandate, because while details are important, it's also useful to maintain a focus on the long-term target, which is a tax system that raises revenue in the most efficient and equitable way possible.
I'm going to start my presentation with five quick suggestions and then move on to a broader proposal.
First, on the GST, strong efforts should be made to harmonize the GST with provincial retail sales taxes in provinces that have not done so. Evidence strongly suggests that business investment would grow.
Second, on capital gains, the proposal to allow deferral of capital gains needs really careful consideration. As the income trust experience has shown us, problems can arise when one type of capital income is taxed differently from other types.
Third, the extension of boutique tax credits for expenditures such as sports and transit passes should stop. While these might be popular in some circles, I don't think they're a good tax policy.
Fourth, I urge you to consider a role for environmental taxation. Environmental taxes are supported by a very broad spectrum of economists. The recent initiatives of the government here in British Columbia in this area should provide some encouragement to our federal politicians in this area.
Fifth and finally, I would like to address the issue of deductibility for registered education savings plans. I understand that legislatively this has been killed. Good. As tax policy, this idea of RESP deductibility is folly, and as education policy, it is farce.
While I believe all five of these items deserve careful consideration, I'm going to defer further comment on them until the time allocated for questions. I'm very happy to speak in more detail about those. But for the rest of my time, I'd like to talk about more fundamental reform that could be considered.
The income tax system that we have today in Canada was built on the recommendations of the royal commission on taxation from the 1960s, commonly referred to as the Carter commission. The backbone of the Carter commission was the idea that income from all sources should be treated equivalently. Whether it's a capital gain, earned income, social benefits, scholarship income, it should all go in the same pot. Economists call this comprehensive income taxation, but it's often distilled down to the phrase “a buck is a buck”.
In theory, there are two principal merits to this type of system. First, there's a sense of equity embedded within it. No matter what is the source of one's economic power, it is treated equally. Second, in theory, it can generate efficiency gains because it avoids preferential treatment of certain types of income, so there's no incentive for individuals to rearrange their affairs and decisions in order to channel their incomes through preferred income categories.
Whatever the merits in theory, the complexity of implementing such a system has proven difficult, especially with respect to capital income. Moreover, the greater mobility of capital that has arisen since the 1960s brings into question whether the Carter framework still resonates with Canada's needs in 2008.
An alternative is available. One alternative is referred to as the “dual income tax”. A dual income tax combines a progressive schedule for the taxation of labour with a separate flat schedule for capital income. Corporate income, capital gains, interest, and dividend income could all be taxed at the exact same rate.
A dual income tax has been in place in Sweden and other Nordic countries since the early 1990s. Aspects of this system are also in place in Belgium, Ireland, the Netherlands, the United States, and elsewhere.
What are the advantages of a dual income tax system? I see three. First is simplification. The complex rules for the taxation of capital income create vast administrative challenges as inventive accountants and lawyers find ways to avoid taxation. By taxing all capital income at the same rate, much of this waste can be avoided.
Second is neutrality. A primary goal for tax policy is to avoid changing decisions about how and when to invest. By taxing all capital income in a simple and equal way, neutrality in investment decisions can be achieved.
Finally, it allows some freedom in the setting of the tax rate on capital income from concerns about equity. With comprehensive income taxation, any attempt to make Canada more attractive as a location for investment dollars by lowering tax rates runs into the problem that tax rates on labour income must be lowered as well. By separating the taxation of labour income from that of capital income, an appropriate rate for each can be chosen.
Let me close by giving you two concrete examples of how a dual income tax system could make the Canadian tax system better. First, consider the income trust episode. At its root, the problem originated in the lopsided treatment of interest income compared to corporate dividend income. The recent changes to the dividend tax credit and corporate tax rates have restored some of the balance for now. But under a dual income tax such a problem couldn't occur, because all types of capital income are automatically going to be treated equally. This might well put an army of tax accountants and tax lawyers out of work, as it renders the search for tax advantage less fruitful, but that's a good thing for our economy, because we can put those minds to more productive use.
For the second concrete example, consider income inequality. In work with my colleagues David Green and Marc Frenette, of Statistics Canada , we have documented a sharp increase in pre-tax and transfer income inequality since 1980 in Canada. The greatest source of this continued increase in income inequality is from labour income. The labour earnings of the highly paid are increasing very quickly. But taxing these big earners at higher rates is difficult, because it means we will also increase the tax on capital income and potentially scare away investment.
So a dual income tax can solve this problem by freeing the tax system to continue to tax labour incomes progressively, without having the fear of scaring away capital investment. Of course a dual income tax would raise several problems in implementation. Potential difficulties might arise in the treatment of the self-employed, pensions and savings, federal-provincial concerns, and various international tax issues, to name just a few. I admit that today I don’t have the answers for all those problems, but I do know that the potential gains of a dual income tax for Canada make it worth while to consider such a change. If it is good enough for a progressive, small, open resource-based economy like Sweden, it might be good enough for Canada. I therefore advocate serious study of a dual income tax.
Thank you for your time and attention. I'm happy to answer your questions.