Thank you very much for rescheduling.
I sent on a bit of a PowerPoint deck. I hope you have it. I will walk you through a few thoughts here.
I've decided I'm going to make just two points. One is going to be related to a plea, essentially, to consider a value-based formulary for Canada. The second is on our unused assets for post-market surveillance.
My colleagues have covered the rare-disease, designer-drug, genomic-based therapies better than I can, so I will not go in that direction. Let me speak to the first two points.
Presently in Canada there is a patchwork. If you're institutionalized, your drugs are free; if you're in the community, it varies by province as to whether or not your drugs are covered. All provinces set up a formulary, meaning those drugs we'll cover and those we won't. For the most part they're covering about 70% or 80% of the drugs that are approved for consideration in Canada.
They do so for what I call the vulnerable subpopulations, by and large—seniors, who use a lot of drugs; people on social assistance; and there may be some other very high-cost drug therapies, but this varies from province to province.
They can't afford it, because seniors are a big group, and so what they always do is attach what I call a copay to it. They say that you'll have to pay a part of this, because otherwise...we want to control the demand for something that may be misused or abused.
I want to take you down to an example of this. In this particular slide, I show you an example of a person who was 25 and was diagnosed as schizophrenic at age 24. This is an architect who had asthma. The person was put on risperidone. That drug costs $140 a month. The inhaled steroid for asthma is $120 a month. From time to time the person has sleeping problems, so that drug is lorazepam, and it costs $35 a month.
If you look at the cost sharing, which goes anywhere from zero to 35% across Canada, 25% was applied in Quebec. They have to pay the most for their anti-psychotic drugs, they have to pay the least for their sleeping medication, and somewhere in between for the steroid to control asthma. Tell me if that makes any sense whatsoever.
When Quebec put in place essentially an increase in that cost share, they saw a very rapid decline—that's shown in the graphic, figure 2 on the “Current Practice” slide—in the use of these essential medications. It was associated with an increase in hospitalizations and emergency department visits.
This is not really a surprise, in fact, because these drugs are essential to control chronic conditions, and they work. If they were being misused—say you run around and take insulin just on a whim—you would see no change in your health status, but if you really need it, you're going to get into trouble pretty quickly. That's exactly what they saw.
The argument I'm trying to make here is that we need to provide, if we want to make sense of what we're doing here, a value-based formulary that says, let's make essential medications that we know control disease free; let's make them available to our population. Let's negotiate the best prices possible in Canada, because we pay sometimes five times as much for an essential drug as other countries. Let's go after that, and let's be parsimonious.
Not every drug gets in—not the 70% that we're used to doing—but let's say the absolutely essential drugs that we know work and that keep people well and working in our community; let's make that our goal to start with. Then we can actually add the cost share to those that potentially could be misused, such as my taking a proton pump inhibitor because I ate too much at the last wedding I went to—that kind of thing.
This is what I'm pushing for. In fact, there are experiments now demonstrating that this actually produces better value for money—I think this is the key here, because we're all afraid that this is going to bankrupt us— and better health outcomes for the community at large.
That's my first case. I've actually suggested here that this value-based formulary essentially be free and that we attach the copays to drugs that could be used or misused in other ways.
Just applying that thinking, I want to make the case for parsimony. If you look at Canada, one of our biggest problems is uncomplicated hypertension, meaning that we're getting older, we're getting fatter, and we tend to have this problem.
What is Canada doing right now? I provide a bit of a breakdown on the slide called “Impact of Value-Based Formulary”. We're spending $2 billion on the treatment of uncomplicated hypertension—just that alone—per year.
If you look at the drugs that we're doing, they vary in price from $173 per person, per year, for a thiazide diuretic to $427 for a multiple drug therapy or for an ARP.
Does that make sense to you? Could we be smarter and say that we're going to give the thiazide diuretic free, and for all the other drugs you're going to have a copay attached to it? At least we'd know that we have an effective drug out there that could treat uncomplicated hypertension. If we did that, and even if we increased the use of thiazide diuretics by 25%, we would save $412 million a year. It makes sense for us to do something along that line.
That's not to say that it's without politics, but at least we have the evidence. We have the scientific evidence to support these decisions.
I will move on to my second point, which is that we're going to do this right and have a national approach to our pharmaceutical strategy, we need a value-based formulary first, and you must have a smart post-market surveillance system second. I am going to make the case here that Canada has some of the best assets in the world, which we've failed to use systematically. I think it's time we use them in a strategic way.
The first thing that happens when a drug gets approved is that it gets thrown out into the market, and people can prescribe it as they wish. If we want to look at off-label use, that was the origin of the unfortunate circumstances that lead to Vanessa's death. Approximately one in 10 drugs is going to be used off-label, meaning that the regulator didn't approve it for that indication. Of those drugs, not all of them lack scientific evidence, but the majority do. A little less than one in 10 will not have scientific evidence for the use of that indication.
It's a bit of a social experimentation that's going on. Sometimes that's a good thing and you discover things you wouldn't have normally discovered. The bad news is that when you are prescribing drugs without scientific evidence, you don't know what their effectiveness is, and you don't know what their risk is.
One of my colleagues did a study on this and looked at the rate of adverse events for off-label use of drugs without scientific evidence. It's quite a bit higher, as you can see in the graph for adverse events, because people are prescribing off-label. Are they doing this intentionally? Probably not. They probably don't know what the scientific evidence is or is not, and they may not have the most up-to-date information on that fact.
What do we do about that? One thing is that we'd better start monitoring off-label use, and we'd better start monitoring adverse drug events that are occurring in the population.
This next deck shows you the adverse drug event reporting requirement. What we know about adverse drug event reporting is that of all the adverse events that are reported, a small proportion, less than 5%, are recorded. Of all those that are occurring, very few are reported. Why is that? Well, it's onerous, quite frankly. No one pays anybody to do that, no one knows where the form is, etc. You can make it mandatory, which is the suggestion from the new regulations, but I think there's a smarter way of doing that.
If we look at our unused resources for doing this, first of all, we have a national health information organization that collects information, and could do so almost in real time, from everybody across Canada. It has agreements with all the provinces. It's called the Canadian Institute for Health Information. That's benefit number one.
Second, we have Health Infoway that invested heavily in creating data repositories for a population-based repository of all drugs prescribed and dispensed, all labs, and all diagnostic imaging.
Third, they've invested in electronic medical records. Now we have the digital information to start putting together a method of monitoring what drugs are being prescribed, what they are being prescribed for—meaning if we can monitor off-label indications—and when they are being stopped and changed because they're not working, or the person is experiencing an adverse drug event. We can capture all that information. Why? It's because we have these players in place. We've made these investments. We just need to pull it together into a national reporting system, and we have the talent in Canada to make sense out of that information.
Finally, we've just invested $50 million in having Infoway build a national prescription system. We can start capturing why this drug was prescribed, why it is being stopped or changed, and we'll know in real time. I've shown you an example of a screen that does exactly that. These are being built into electronic prescribing systems. If you stopped this drug, you need to let the pharmacist know you stopped it, because they're going to keep on dispensing it if you didn't tell them. The person stopped using it because they had an adverse drug event. And what was it? In this case, it was that the person had epilepsy, a seizure, from this medication. That can all be captured. You stop the drug; you need to tell people you stopped it, and that it was stopped for such and such reason, so that people won't re-prescribe it.
I'm thinking that we have all the pieces together and that it's simply a matter of trying to make use of all these pieces through a strategy that can be developed nationally for the country.
Thank you for your time.