Good afternoon, and thank you very much for the invitation to present.
I'll provide a brief background. I'm Australian. I am a physician and trained as a gastroenterologist a long time ago. My relevant work was that for 10 years I was a member of the national committee in Australia called the Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee. It has been referred to by a couple of my colleagues today. For about eight years I chaired the economics subcommittee of the pharmaceutical benefits advisory committee in Australia, and it's based on that experience that I'm going to make some comments to the committee today.
By way of background, Australia has a national medicinal drug policy. It's foundational, and it has four arms.
The first, and really the one we're talking about today, is timely access to the priority medicines that Australians need at a cost that individuals and the community can afford. That's really the drug benefit program. It operates off the schedule of pharmaceutical benefits, which is the Australian national formulary. The committee that I was privileged to be a member of, and the committee I chaired, had responsibility for overseeing the maintenance of that. I'm going to call it a schedule, if you don't mind, but it's equivalent I think to a formulary.
The other three arms of the national medicinal drug policy are important, however, because I don't think that a national formulary exists in isolation.
Importantly, and this has been addressed before, this policy around quality use of medicines is the term that's used. It's sometimes called rational drug use, but that could be interpreted different ways.
Quality use of medicines is the responsibility of a national prescribing service. Not only is there a national formulary, a national drug benefit program, but there's also a national pharmaceutical prescribing service which provides educators who work in particular but not exclusively with family practices and large groups of family practitioners called divisions of general practice in Australia. They also work with specialists.
The third arm is the arm that most countries nearly all possess, and that is some assessment of efficacy, safety, and quality of medicines. That's the role of Health Canada in Canada. It was the Therapeutic Goods Administration in Australia.
The fourth arm, and I think an important one, is at the same time trying to balance the need to maintain a responsible and viable medicines industry. I'm not here to advocate for the industry, but just to make the point that a balanced national medicinal policy really does to some degree have to have some representation of these four functions in it.
Within that comprehensive policy—a very serious policy that was introduced by a Labour government, but it continued under different Conservative governments—the pharmaceutical benefits scheme sits.
I thought I would talk a little bit about that scheme. Why talk about the Australian scheme? Is it the best in the world? No, I actually don't think it is, but I do know it well so I can speak from that experience. I think it is an archetypal example of a scheme.
Also, I have worked for some time in both countries, and there are similarities between Australia and Canada in terms of social structures and values, a national single-payer health care system, albeit that Australia has also private health care, not just pharmaceutical coverage, but more broadly. The similarities in the system are really quite striking except for the lack of a national pharmaceutical benefits scheme in Canada. It's for that reason it probably does represent something of a comparator and maybe some useful lessons.
The schedule, if I can call it that, the formulary really provides medicines to meet the priority health needs of the population. It's complete population coverage. Everybody who's eligible gets the drugs. There are no exceptions to it. There's no postal code prescribing. In Australia, if you live in the Northern Territory or New South Wales, you get the same coverage.
I mentioned it sits within the national medicinal drug policy, but it's also supported by very strong legislation. It comes under section 85 of the National Health Act in Australia. The legislative effect of the legislation is important. The committee is named in the legislation, and the committee makes a recommendation to the federal health minister about which drugs should be declared on the national schedule. The point, however, is that the minister cannot declare a drug on the schedule without a positive recommendation from the committee. That helps keep the evidence-based process alive, but it also to some extent protects the minister in a political sense because the minister can always say, “Well, I haven't received a positive recommendation. That's why we're not subsidizing this drug.” Many ministers, while I was there, and there were quite a few, certainly used the committee, I think appropriately, as a shield at a time when they were under pressure for certain drugs not being listed.
It's an evidence-based evaluation rather similar to what happens in Canada. I'm not going to talk at length about that; you've heard about that. It had responsibility not only for looking at cost effectiveness and comparative effectiveness and making a recommendation to the minister, but it also had responsibility for looking at the total cost to the community and the total health impact. These are really important. What was the public health impact of this new drug being listed? What was the total cost going to be, and where were the savings going to be experienced, if there were going to be savings?
Two more components I think are relevant. The final price of the drug was negotiated by a separate pricing authority that wouldn't go to work until a positive recommendation came from the expert committee. That pricing authority would work across the table from industry and negotiate that final price. Now, there was nowhere the industry could go. If they couldn't get a negotiated priced, they couldn't get the drug subsidized in the country for what was then 22 million people. In other words, there was a considerable bargaining power across that table. I know that from the experience of working with it, because I chaired the economic committee that provided the pricing authority with the information that it needed.
The final thing to note is that when a price had been negotiated and there was clearly a positive recommendation to declare the drug on the schedule, it was finally a cabinet decision. The minister would take it to cabinet if the total cost implication was more than $10 million a year, really quite a low threshold. To be honest, I'm not sure if that's been adjusted upward, but the point was that finally cabinet would make the decision to spend the money.
Sometimes they said no when the committee had said, “Yes, this is value for money.” I'll give you an example. The committee recommended anti-smoking therapy, nicotine replacement therapies. The pricing authority negotiated what was a reasonable price. The total cost was reasonable, it seemed, but cabinet decided—and I'm not saying rightly or wrongly, just describing—that they did not support that. They felt the smokers were paying for the cigarettes so they should be able to pay for the nicotine replacement therapy. You can see there's a sort of logic there. I didn't support it, but that was the argument.
This has been in operation for a long time. Let me say right up front that Australia introduced this in the 1950s, ahead of comprehensive medicare that was really only introduced about 1982-83, really quite long after Canada. It's had a pharmaceutical benefit scheme since the 1950s, so it was there. It was foundational. I quite accept that it's harder to introduce a program when you already have a patchwork—and I don't mean that in a demeaning way—of systems in Canada, and it is different from starting from a clean sheet. Going from the Canadian system to an Australian system is tougher than starting with nothing and getting to where Australia is now.
I have some final concluding comments and examples, I think, of the power of a national system.
The average per capita spend in 2011 dollars, purchase parity corrected, in Australia was $588, that's OECD, as against $771 in Canada, so almost $200 less per person. You can see how that translates into quite a large sum. That's the average across the population.
That's my spiel about how that works. I don't think it's the best. I just know it, and I think there's some relevance.
I am just going to give two very brief examples of diseases that I think illustrate the advantage of a national program.
One is hepatitis C. Australia has announced that it's going to eradicate hepatitis C through the pharmaceutical benefits scheme. These drugs are expensive. Anne has mentioned them already. They do work.
We know from the experience of HIV that treating people stops them from infecting other people, as well as helping them. That seems to be the case for the new drugs for hepatitis C. By treating everybody, you also cut the chances of somebody becoming reinfected by someone else, but it depends on drugs, not vaccines. It's hard to do that without a national program. Imagine negotiating that in Canada through the provinces' and territories' non-insured health benefits. It's a hard thing to do.
My final example is diabetes. My wife is chief of endocrinology at Sunnybrook Health Sciences Centre. She was chief of endocrinology in an Australian teaching hospital, and moved from one position to the other. She treats diabetes, as well as everything else, in the same way. In Canada, in Toronto, she has a fridge for insulin. She had the same fridge in Australia to start people off and give them their first ever dose of insulin. She keeps the fridge in Toronto for the people who cannot afford their insulin. She sees five or six people per month in her practice alone who cannot afford insulin, a life-saving drug that was discovered by Banting and Best in Toronto, not very far from where she practises.
This is an extraordinary situation. She has to hand out free insulin to patients.