Thank you very much.
With respect to my presentation, I'd just like to warn you that I found out I'd been invited to appear before the committee just last week. I had to submit my slides for translation the next day, so I've recycled a presentation I gave last month to McGill University's Faculty of Law for their Intellectual Property Week.
I am reusing that presentation, and since it was originally done in English, I am going to speak in English. My apologies to the francophones.
I'll discuss the Canadian pharmaceutical sector from the innovation economy to corporate welfare. Basically, I'm going to focus on the first two points, the evolution of the Canadian pharmaceutical sector and then the cost and benefits of innovation policy in Canada.
There's a bit of a “done it” narrative, which, in fact, is mostly true. Before 1987, before the implementation of the new patent regime under the Mulroney government, the Canadian pharmaceutical sector focused mostly on generics. Then there were the negotiations to implement a new patent law, but at the same time negotiating conditions, meaning that if we extended privileges to drug companies in order to increase research and development, these were the conditions that we would impose. Basically we were asking for a 10% ratio of R and D to sales. At the time, the Patented Medicine Prices Review Board was created as a watchdog to make sure that this deal was respected.
What is wrong with this narrative? It hasn't been true since 2000 or 2001. This R and D-to-sales ratio is one of the most interesting indicators showing the intensity of research and development in the pharmaceutical sector. It's basically the proportion of sales that is being reinvested in research and development. We see that after implementation of the new patent law, it was really successful. There was an important increase in the R and D-to-sales ratio. Then things started to decline, and we did not enforce the 10% R and D-to-sales ratio. In fact, now the situation is worse than when we implemented the system in 1988, worse than when we just changed the patent law at the time.
Now, we would like to compare ourselves to leaders in terms of pharmaceutical innovation and R and D, such as France, Germany, the United Kingdom, but if we compare this R and D-to-sales ratio, we more comparable to Cyprus and Romania, in fact.
If you look at the evolution of revenues versus investment in research and development in the pharmaceutical sector, there's been a strong increase in the evolution of revenues. Sales are going up. This sector is very profitable; it's making more and more money in Canada. But if you look at it in terms of how that translates into more research and development, well, R and D has been stagnating, and in fact declining in the last years.
So providing more money, putting more money into this sector, giving it more privileges in order to get some R and D, is not how things work. This is not Canada. These are the 10 largest pharmaceutical companies appearing on Fortune 500, as compared to dominant companies in other industrial sectors. What we have seen since the mid-1980s is a strong differential increase in the rate of profit of drug companies. Overall, this sector remains a very profitable sector when compared to other industrial sectors.
What does the fact that the sector is profitable mean in terms of R and D, in terms of innovation? Looking at the cost structure over time, or its evolution from the 1970s to 2006, we see that there has been an important decrease in manufacturing and a bit of an increase in terms of research and development, which reflects the importance of tax credits provided in the 1980s for R and D investment. What we see, in fact, is a major shift or surge in marketing and administrative expenses.
If you look, for example, at Canada—this is a bit dated, but it represents well the proportion of employment in the sector—only 17% of employment in the pharmaceutical sector is R and D for Rx and D members, and the 3% is for distribution, marketing, and sales, or mostly sales reps.
What does that mean in terms of innovation? Well, it's very difficult to measure therapeutic innovation. One measure that is sometimes used, which I don't really like, is the global introduction of new molecular entities. Well, it's going down, but this is normal. In the 1960s you could enter anything on the market, for example, thalidomide for pregnant women, and thank God things have changed since then.
But the question is, even if there are fewer drugs on the market, does that mean they are better drugs that represent greater therapeutic advances? There's a fantastic French medical journal called Prescrire, and every year they assess every new drug that enters the market. They look at whether it represents a therapeutic advance or not compared to existing drugs. The blue section is the section representing positive therapeutic value. Those with neutral therapeutic value—the bulk—are shown in red, basically the me-too drugs that do not bring any therapeutic advantage as compared to the already existing drugs. And the negative therapeutic value is the drugs where the harms dwarf the benefits, drugs like Vioxx or Avandia, that according to Prescrire simply shouldn't be on the market. So for Prescrire, it's not clear if we have an improvement or a regression of the pharmacopoeia.
Now, should Canada provide more generous policy for its pharmaceutical sector? In order to answer this question it's very important to understand what we are providing right now. We have the patent system, yes, but over that we also have a series of innovation policies for that sector. There are tax credits for R and D, there's the way we price patented drugs in Canada. We had a 15-year rule in Quebec and we replaced it with more generous tax credits in Quebec. These are numbers for 2011. We also had some direct subsidies.
Going through this very rapidly—this is based on a report I wrote for Health Canada—if you look at tax credits, Rx and D members say they receive 48% of R and D costs back in tax credits. That represents something like $461 million in 2011.
In terms of pricing policy, we have a weird system for pricing patented drugs in Canada. Basically we look at the median of seven countries, including the four most expensive countries in the world. So Canada has a system where we're always aiming to be the world's fourth most expensive country. Now, if we compare ourselves with European countries such as France or the United Kingdom, for example, we pay 20% more for our patented drugs in Canada than they do in these countries. There's a lot of discussion right now, for example during the CETA negotiations, that Canada should be closer to the European system for its patent system. Well, if you want to be equivalent to Europe, basically start by reducing the cost of your patented drugs by at least 15%.
So if we reorganize pricing policy to be more at par with what is happening in Europe, we could easily save something like $2 billion per year in additional costs. These are the additional costs we're paying right now for our patented drugs.
In terms of the 15-year rule in Quebec, in 2011 the cost was $193 million. Direct subsidies were between $57 million and $75 million in Ontario and Quebec. If we sum all this up, we have tax subsidies, $461 million, and $2.2 billion in different types of subsidies due to the way we price our drugs, direct subsidies, and the 15-year rule.
Now, if we consider that the pharmaceutical R and D in the brand name sector in Canada was $960 million in 2011, and the tax credits were approximately $461 million, it means that the total private spending in R and D, net of tax credits in Canada, was $499 million. So Canadians paid at least $2.2 billion in public financial support in order to generate $499 million in private R and D expenditure, net of tax credits.
This is absolute nonsense. I am a fiscal conservative. I want to get bang for my public buck, and I can't wait for somebody at Industry Canada to wake up and start doing some cost-benefit analysis, because this is pure nonsense here.
I'll skip the part on CETA.
I would like to finish with some numbers on the funding for R and D in the health field.
Now we have an innovation system that is—