Mr. Speaker, I support the main provisions of Bill C-70. They have obviously been written in response to difficulties that have arisen out of initial legislation. They are designed to make life easier for taxpayers, eliminate ambiguities and remove inequities. As such, the provisions are laudable.
A careful study of each provision in the bill was undertaken by Reform research. I spent some time looking at the findings. It turns out the laudable attempts to make the Income Tax Act more equitable and efficient do not offer a perfect solution.
Some of the new provisions conflict with principles developed by Reform Party assemblies where grassroots Reformers have the opportunity to express their views and bind members of caucus. Most involve technical issues and it is not easy to apply simple principles.
My colleague from St. Albert yesterday in his speech on this bill expressed Reform's objection to specific clauses of it. I will not repeat his analysis. Instead, I wish to take this opportunity to do two things. First, I will make the case for the revision of some income tax changes contained in the February budget. Second, I will take up the challenge by the hon. member for Broadview-Greenwood and discuss an alternative system for taxation which would eliminate the need for complicated income tax provisions of the sort contained in Bill C-70.
On the first topic let me read the contents of a letter written to the Minister of Finance by Carol Loughrey, chair of the Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants of Canada. A copy was sent to me as a result of my involvement in the issue. This involvement started when I asked the Minister of Finance a question in the House and he gave me a very unsatisfactory answer.
I have received several letters from other affected parties such as professionals, tax lawyers and accountants. They agree with the points made in the letter by Miss Loughrey and simply elaborate on some of the issues she raised.
Let me now read this letter:
I am writing to convey the CA profession's disappointment and concern regarding the announcement in the budget that individuals with business or professional income will be required to have a December 31 year-end. We have three primary concerns: the removal of the ability to use natural year-ends, an even more compressed workload for our members and the lack of fairness in the changes.
Natural year-ends
Many businesses have year-ends other than December 31 because of the nature of their business rather than for tax planning purposes. The tax system should not impose a year-end that for these businesses make no business sense. For example, forcing a retail business to have a calendar year-end would impose a significant workload increase during their busiest season and would impede effective measurement and evaluation of their business performance.
Where a business wished to preserve a natural year end it could do so only by incorporating. For businesses which can incorporate this would mean additional legal and accounting costs. Many professionals, including chartered accountants, are prevented by law from incorporating. However, even where the professionals are permitted to incorporate, the budget will require them to maintain a December 31 year-end.
The workload of many of our members is by far the greatest during the first four months of the year. Our members are already strained coping with the demand for audit and accounting services, tax return preparation, including personal tax returns information returns such as T4s, T5s, workers' compensation returns, payroll tax returns and PST and GST returns. Moving all professional and unincorporated
business year-ends, and some incorporated business year-ends, to December 31 will add considerably to that already compressed workload. We are concerned that the changes will seriously limit the ability of our members to properly serve their clients and could turn smaller practices into seasonable businesses.
Fairness
The budget refers to the need to improve the fairness of the tax system by treating professional and business income the same as employment income. However, there are important ways in which income from a profession or business is not the same as income from employment. Professionals and business people assume risk by gathering business capital and investing in their business, a task that will be more difficult without the tax deferral; they lease or purchase a business location and business equipment; they employ others; they must protect against liability; they must carry on their business without benefit of unemployment insurance or protection against disability or severance. A fair tax system should recognize that the self-employed are not the same as employees and that they should not be treated the same.
We are also concerned about the fairness of the transitional provisions. We believe they are too restrictive and will impose an unfair tax burden. It would appear that the ten-year reserve will not be available in certain situations, such as where an individual changes firms or changes from being a partner to sole proprietor or vice versa. The loss of this reserve in such circumstances would be inequitable and would create a barrier to the natural movement of individuals, interfering with their ability to carry on their business or practice as they see fit or as conditions require. Furthermore, it is unfair that the income to be included over the transition period is to be taxed at the individual's highest marginal tax rate rather than the average rate and that individuals could lose one year of eligibility to make RRSP contributions. We believe that the fairness of these measures could be improved through additional transitional measures.
Finally, it is very troubling that the changes are retrospective. We are already within the 1995 fiscal calendar year-the changes will have a real and harmful impact on taxpayers who had arranged their affairs in accordance with the law as it stood before the budget.
In the last few minutes I have been reading a letter which had been sent to the Minister of Finance by the institute of chartered accountants.
I fully agree with the technical assessment of the problems with the budget provisions identified in this letter and urge the Minister of Finance to make the changes in the Budget Implementation Act to correct the inequities and the inefficiencies created by this action.
I want to add the following political judgment which people like the writers of this letter cannot express but probably agree with.
The Minister of Finance justified his budget measures as a step for greater equity. We all know equity is in the eyes of the beholder. The letter I read referred to the difficulties that arise from the arbitrary lumping together of employment and self-employment income which is used to make this equity argument. I agree this is rather arbitrary.
However, my main additional argument is this provision is simply a one time tax grab motivated by the desire to raise revenue, lower the deficit and avoid the need for spending cuts. The people of Canada in their taxpayer rallies and even in their presentations to the finance committee of the House made it abundantly clear they preferred spending cuts over tax increases to eliminate the deficit. Reformers agreed.
The Minister of Finance thought he could raise taxes on what he considered to be a relatively small group of professionals by justifying the tax grab to the general public as a measure of increasing equity.
The minister may have underestimated both the strength of the opposition from the affected professionals and their accountants and tax advisers. I hope he takes note of the legitimate objections I have raised.
As an economist I see these objections as quantifiable costs that need to be examined in relation to the value of the one time tax revenue increase. I am convinced the ratio of social costs to benefits makes this tax provision one of the least efficient alternatives for raising revenue and more broadly eliminating the deficit.
As I noted already, Bill C-70 stands in support of the widely accepted view that Canada's tax system is too complicated. The readjustment of accounting years for professionals just discussed is only another example.
Every country's tax code becomes more complex every year. Inequities and inefficiencies of the existing code have to be corrected. Dynamic new developments in the economy and financial intermediations require adjustment. There are developments abroad that need to be reflected.
Every country periodically faces the need for a major overhaul of its tax code when the complexity has become so large that it threatens to strangle incentive, drown the private sector in red tape and divert too many of the country's best and brightest accountants and lawyers into activities which essentially are socially unproductive.
I believe, much like the member for Broadview-Greenwood, Canada has reached this stage. There are several members of the Reform caucus, in particular my colleague from Calgary Centre, who strongly support such efforts.
The proposed overhaul of Canada's tax code should be aimed at the creation of what alternatively has been called a flat or proportional tax, a single tax. An intensive study of such a new tax system should start now, not just because of the excessive complexity of Canada's tax code but, more important, because of new developments in the United States.
To make this point I cannot do better than read from a Globe and Mail editorial from April 24, 1995, unsigned:
There is a time bomb ticking under the Canadian welfare state. It is not the debt, nor the aging of the population, though these are threats enough. It is the coming revolution in the U.S. tax system.
Already, several large northeastern states have embarked on radical tax cutting programs. Now leading federal politicians in Congress and on the presidential campaign trail are promising not just to overhaul the federal income tax but to abolish it.
Dick Armey, leader of the Republican majority in the House of Representatives, is pushing the most moderate-relatively speaking-reform plan, a flat tax that would eliminate most deductions and credits in favour of a single low tax rate for everybody. Mr. Armey figures it is possible to get the rate down to 20 or even 17 per cent this way without running up the deficit. The tax form would be the size of a postcard.
The immediate objection to this is that it would kill progressivity: that is, the principle that richer people should pay a larger share of their income in tax. But rising marginal tax rates are not the only way to make the system progressive; you can also do it through the tax base. Mr. Armey's plan would exempt roughly the first $20,000 of individual income from tax. Someone earning $25,000 would pay Mr. Armey's 20 per cent flat tax on only one-fifth of his income, for an effective tax rate of 4 per cent. At $40,000, he would pay tax on half his income, for an effective tax rate of 10 per cent. At $100,000, the effective rate would be 16 per cent.
I have enough time to conclude with another excerpt:
Too radical? Dreamsville? Think again. Not only do the Republicans control both houses of Congress, but all of the GOP candidates for president have endorsed one or other of these proposals. This has enormous significance for Canada. We do not have to slash tax rates to U.S. levels. But we do have to stay within hailing distance. At 17 per cent, U.S. personal income tax rates would be a half to a third of the top combined rate in Canada. Indeed, a flatter, simpler tax system would be desirable in its own right. At the least, it would free some of the brightest minds in the country, now employed as tax lawyers and accountants, for more productive work.
I would like to end my quotations here, except to mention that the hon. member for Broadview-Greenwood is mentioned by name in this editorial, and I congratulate him.
I would like to make a couple of comments in closing. Please note that in my short remarks I do not endorse the particular version of a flat tax described in the Globe and Mail editorial or advanced by the hon. member for Broadview-Greenwood or by my colleague from Calgary Centre. The reason is, as is the case with many appealingly simple ideas, there are devils in the details and there is a danger that advocates of policies end up not telling quite all. For this reason, I urge the immediate start of a major study of the proposals for a simplified flat tax system.
During the study and public hearings on the subject I think it will become immediately obvious that the widespread support for such a measure is based on false assumptions. Few people, if asked, will object to a new system that promises to lower their tax rate from the present high one. Often quoted are the marginal tax rates on incomes in British Columbia, which are now around 53 per cent for the federal and provincial rates combined. The most important false assumption is that the lower flat rate, normally discussed in this context, is deceptively low. In the Canadian system every federal rate will automatically be increased by about 50 per cent due to the provincial income tax laws, even if the provinces also adopt a flat tax system.
The second and perhaps most fundamental point is that Canada's fiscal problems stem from overspending. Based on reliable estimates, the combined spending of all governmental jurisdictions equals about one-half of our national income. That is why tax freedom day falls in July.
The government has to raise the revenue to pay for this spending. As it does, by definition, the average tax burden on the average Canadian will remain about 50 per cent of his or her income. No tax reform can alter this basic fact. People who are seduced into believing otherwise by the promise of a flat rate, much lower than the current marginal rate they pay, have to face the fact that the government has to get its revenue somewhere. Most likely, it will get it from exactly the same people and in the same amounts as it does now. There are no large hidden incomes that will be tapped by the flat tax and there are no magic solutions to the problem of overspending.
Finally, I would like to note that the idea of a flat tax has been around for a long time. It once served as a basic model for reform in the United States and in Canada in the 1980s. As it turned out, by the time all of the trade-offs between efficiency and equity were studied thoroughly, both countries ended up with modified flat tax rates; that is, three broad tiers and relatively small marginal increases rather than the previous scale with many incremental steps and very high ultimate marginal rates. The idea that basic personal exemptions result in progressive average rates, as noted in the Globe and Mail editorial, did not carry the day during the deliberations in these two countries. I am worried that it may also not do so in the future if we have hearings again.
These and the other concerns I have about the merit of a flat tax do not mean that the system should not be studied. The hope of eliminating the kinds of complex tax codes contained in Bill C-70 make it very worth while. In the meantime, I urge the proponents of the tax to be cautious in their advocacy, much as I have done in the past and in my brief discussion today.